Much of the economic data produced and released by national statistical agencies around the world represent a labyrinth for investors to navigate through and interpret for the purposes of making informed decisions about the trajectory of asset prices. Many market economists whose job is to decipher and communicate the key themes of macroeconomic data releases to investors and the broader community do themselves a disservice by assuming too much prior knowledge and confusing their audience with jargon laden observations. In this post, Skeptikoi hopes to demystify some of the jargon surrounding the most complex of all data releases, the National Accounts.
What does it actually mean to say that Australia's gross domestic product (GDP) expanded by 0.8% in real or inflation adjusted terms in the December quarter to be 2.8% than a year earlier. GDP is a measure of the flow of production that occurs in a particular period. The ABS avoids double counting by deducting from the value of output the value of intermediate goods and services used up in the production process. The term gross refers to the fact that the flow of production does not adjust for deprecation or wear and tear of fixed capital such as buildings and capital equipment that occurs in production processes.
GDP is measured three ways: production, income and expenditure. Most of the higher frequency data produced by the Australian Bureau of Statistics (and other statistical agencies around the world) - including retail trade and building approvals releases - relates to the expenditure measure of GDP. The production measure is based on surveys of business, while the income measure is based on the income earned by the household sector (employee compensation), business sector (profits) and governments (tax revenue).
The income measure clearly illustrates why profitability and stock market performance more generally are not necessarily related to a country's GDP growth. The GDP or gross value add of the retail sector for instance, represents the sum of labour earnings earned, after tax profit generated and tax paid to governments. A rise in wage rates for retail sector workers - without an offsetting reduction in the number of hours worked in the industry - could boost labour earnings in the sector but depress profitability.
For investors, the distinction between nominal and real GDP is important but still poorly understood. Nominal GDP is simply the dollar value of production, while the real estimate adjusts for inflation. Statistical agencies that produce National Accounts and economists tend to focus on the headline GDP measure in real or inflation adjusted terms. This is reasonable when comparing measures of production across time periods that have materially different rates of inflation. But inflationary pressures have remained low in Australia and other developed economies for over two decades now. Further, companies generate nominal revenues and earn nominal profits or cash flows. Consequently, nominal GDP is more relevant than real GDP for understanding trends in aggregate sales revenues.
Skeptikoi has been critical of the Reserve Bank of Australia (RBA) in the past because excessively tight monetary policy has contributed to a nominal 'recession'; average annual growth in nominal GDP of less than 4%. The 1.6% quarterly growth in nominal GDP was a welcome development. Nonetheless, by Skeptikoi's measure, the Australian economy remained in a nominal recession for the second consecutive calendar year; nominal GDP expanded by 3.5% in 2013 following 3.4% growth in 2012. This represents the weakest two successive years of nominal GDP growth in over two decades and growth in 2013 remained well below the twenty year median of over 6%. In an era where nominal GDP growth targeting is gaining some currency around the world, the persistent weakness in the nominal economy constitutes a fail for the RBA.
The weak environment for nominal GDP has undermined the ability of companies to achieve strong revenue expansion and instead they have resorted to margin expansion to boost profitability. The profits of non-financial corporations in particular jumped by 4.7% in the December quarter to be 20% higher than the pre-financial crisis peak of 2008. Profits of financial corporations posted modest quarterly growth of 0.5%, but are also around 20% higher than the pre-financial crisis peak.
Australian companies in aggregate have achieved strong margin expansion by aggressively managing operating expenses, reducing capital investment where feasible and boosting productivity. The National Accounts confirm the cost discipline that has been evident at the company level in recent reporting seasons. Nominal unit labour costs - which are productivity adjusted wages growth - increased by a modest 0.3% in the December quarter and have been stagnant since March 2012, which has helped to support business sector profit margins. Excluding the financial crisis, one has to go back to the late 1990s for the last extended period of stagnant unit labour costs.
The weakness in unit labour costs and margin expansion owes much to Australia's productivity renaissance in the past three years. Gross value added per hour worked in the market sector expanded by a nominal 1.1% in the December quarter, the strongest quarterly outcome since March 2012. Since March 2011, productivity has expanded at a compound annual rate of over 3%, well above compound annual growth of less than 1% in the five years to March 2011. The last time it grew at or above 3% for a sustained period was over a decade ago.
Of course, the flipside of the productivity renaissance and corporate Australia's aggressive focus on cost containment, is continued weakness in labour market conditions. Aggregate hours worked actually declined marginally in the December quarter and have remained little changed in the past two years, despite unusually strong population growth. Consequently, the unemployment rate has increased to 6% from 5.2% in December 2011.
In summary, the National Accounts reveal a business sector that is prospering despite subdued environment for nominal GDP and revenue expansion in recent years. The strong quarterly increase in nominal GDP is a welcome development but is unlikely to herald the start of a strong recovery if the interim reporting season is anything to go by. Skeptikoi expects cost discipline to continue, as firms increasingly cater to the market's insatiable appetite for income by boosting free cash flows and lifting or maintaining already high dividend payout ratios. Great news for investors; less so for workers and job-seekers.
Skeptikoi
Wednesday, 5 March 2014
Wednesday, 26 February 2014
The Bankers Who Cry Wolf
‘In recent years…a tension has
emerged between reform and growth.
Regulators want to complete the reform in part by having banks hold
substantially more capital, a goal which the financial industry supports. Nonetheless, this vies with the broader aim
of lifting growth by increasing available credit and bank lending.’
Axel Weber, Chairman of Swiss bank, UBS
Most people are familiar with Aesop’s tale of the boy who cried wolf. A bored shepherd boy amuses himself by crying wolf when there is no wolf. He does so twice and villagers come rushing to help each time, only to find that that there is no wolf. When he cries wolf a third time, the villagers believing that he is lying to them once again, ignore him; only this time, a wolf has set upon and scattered the shepherd boy’s flock.
The chorus of bankers complaining about onerous capital requirements reminds Skeptikoi of Aesop’s tale. Two banking and finance academics, Anat Admati and Martin Hellwing have recently published a book (The Bankers’ New Clothes) that exposes the myths surrounding bankers’ cries of wolf. Given that excessive leverage amongst financial institutions propagated the financial crisis, Skeptikoi strongly recommends the book to anyone interested in the safety of the global financial system.
As long as governments and prudential regulators continue to heed bankers' cries of wolf on capital regulation, capital ratios will remain dangerously low. Against ths backdrop, Skeptikoi believes that a crisis of confidence could once again expose the fragility of the global financial system.
Axel Weber, Chairman of Swiss bank, UBS
Most people are familiar with Aesop’s tale of the boy who cried wolf. A bored shepherd boy amuses himself by crying wolf when there is no wolf. He does so twice and villagers come rushing to help each time, only to find that that there is no wolf. When he cries wolf a third time, the villagers believing that he is lying to them once again, ignore him; only this time, a wolf has set upon and scattered the shepherd boy’s flock.
The chorus of bankers complaining about onerous capital requirements reminds Skeptikoi of Aesop’s tale. Two banking and finance academics, Anat Admati and Martin Hellwing have recently published a book (The Bankers’ New Clothes) that exposes the myths surrounding bankers’ cries of wolf. Given that excessive leverage amongst financial institutions propagated the financial crisis, Skeptikoi strongly recommends the book to anyone interested in the safety of the global financial system.
The bankers’
common cry is that they are forced to set aside regulatory capital, which sits
idle on their balance sheet and could otherwise by lent to businesses and
households. The Chairman of Swiss
investment bank UBS suggests that there is a trade-off between regulatory
capital requirements and economic growth.
As seductive as this might sound, it is utter nonsense.
To
understand why, it is important to consider the basic function of a bank as
‘maturity transformation’. On the right
side of a bank’s balance sheet are its liabilities: wholesale debt
funding, customer deposits and common equity that it raises from shareholders. A bank uses these funds to lend to businesses,
households and governments. The loans
are a bank’s assets that obviously sit on the left side of its balance
sheet. There is a mismatch in maturity
between the bank’s assets and liabilities; its assets are typically long term
and illiquid. There is no transparent
price mechanism that reflects and conveys the market value of loans. In contrast, a bank’s liabilities are short
shorter term and liquid; for instance, customer deposits are either at call or
have a term of up to three years, while funds borrowed from wholesale debt
markets have a similar short maturity.
The key
function of a bank is to manage the mismatch in maturity between its assets and
liabilities. It does so primarily by
carefully evaluating prospective borrowers’ ability to make their loan
repayments. To this end, a bank might demand
some form of collateral from the borrower.
A mortgagee has to pay a minimum deposit or down-payment, while banks
typically impose debt covenants on business borrowers that allow the bank to
re-negotiate the terms of the loan if those covenants are breached.
Capital
regulation is concerned with a bank’s mix of liabilities. In banking, capital refers to the amount of
equity raised from shareholders and used to fund a bank’s lending
activities. Why would a prudential
regulator wish to impose constraints on a bank’s funding or liability mix? It gets back to a bank’s delicate task of managing
the maturity mismatch between its long dated illiquid assets (ie. loans) and
short-term liquid liabilities. A bank
that is heavily reliant on short-term funds borrowed from wholesale debt
markets can easily become vulnerable to a crisis of confidence if a large
enough number of business and housing loans it has written have defaulted.
Capital
regulation simply forces banks to have a minimum amount of common equity
(relative to total assets or risk weighted assets) in their liability mix. A crisis of confidence is less likely if a
bank has secured a larger share of its funding from equity or shareholder
capital, which Admati and Hellwig describe as ‘un-borrowed money’. As residual claimants to a bank’s cash flows,
a bank can cease dividend payments to shareholders in the event that it gets
into trouble. Common equity acts as a
buffer or shock absorber in the same way that a large deposit or down-payment
better shields a mortgagee in the event that the value of her house declines.
Bankers
continue to propagate the myth that that capital regulation constrains a bank’s
ability to lend and inhibit credit growth.
Capital requirements do not require banks to set aside capital to sit
idly in their vaults; the need to have a minimum amount of common equity in their
funding mix does not affect the asset side of a bank’s balance sheet, notably
its loans. A bank retains complete
discretion as to whom it lends to, and how much.
Even though
five years have passed since the collapse of US investment bank, Lehman
Brothers, banks’ capital ratios remain woefully inadequate. Basel III has imposed more onerous capital
requirements than its predecessors. Some national prudential regulators –
including the Australian Prudential Regulatory Authority - have imposed even higher capital ratios than recommended by Basel III. Nonetheless, the leverage ratio (common
equity to assets) for Australia’s major banks is typically no higher than
7%. That is, for every $100 worth of
loans written by a typical Australian bank, it holds only $7 of equity. In contrast, the median leverage ratio for
non-financial companies listed on the ASX200 is 50%! The pattern of over-leveraged banks is
similar for US and European banks, whose leverage ratios of around 10% are well
below non-financials of 40%.
Banks that
fund a greater share of their loans with common equity are safer and should be
able to better withstand a run or a financial crisis. Why then don’t banks hold more equity
capital? The answer is simple; taxpayer
funded guarantees on deposits and systemically important banks encourage banks
to take on excessive risk. And
government guarantees allow banks to borrow funds from wholesale debt markets
at cheaper rates. The lure of cheap debt
funding is far too tempting for most bankers and trumps any systemic concerns that high
leverage could undermine the stability of the financial system.As long as governments and prudential regulators continue to heed bankers' cries of wolf on capital regulation, capital ratios will remain dangerously low. Against ths backdrop, Skeptikoi believes that a crisis of confidence could once again expose the fragility of the global financial system.
Friday, 31 January 2014
The Restless Investor, Trust and the Global Cycle
On face value, Woodside Petroleum and Macquarie Bank
have little in common. One is an oil and
gas company, the other an investment bank.
For a long time, investors have considered both to be growth stocks; their
revenue growth is projected to exceed growth in the broader economy. Woodside is exposed to strongly growing
demand for liquefied natural gas (LNG) from Asia while Macquarie has
transformed itself into a global asset manager, exposed to the growing demand
for private pensions among ageing developed country populations.
Both companies raised their dividend payout ratios in
2013 and announced they would maintain a higher than normal payout ratio going
forward. Investors normally interpret
higher dividends from growth stocks as a signal of lower future growth
prospects and mark them down accordingly.
But these announcements were favourably received by the market and each
stock delivered higher returns than the ASX200 over the course of 2013.
In recent years, companies globally have deferred or
abandoned growth options and increasingly returned cash or capital to
shareholders via higher dividend payments and stock repurchases. Skeptikoi believes this phenomenon stems
largely from the financial crisis and the rise of the restless investor, with
an assist from the disappointingly slow global recovery which has dulled
investors’ appetite for risk.
The defining feature of the restless investor is a
loss of trust arising from the financial trauma of 2008. Research studies have shown that low levels
of trust discourage stock market participation.
Trust might have an important bearing on the finding that macroeconomic
experiences can have life-long effects on attitudes towards risk; investors who
experience low market-wide returns in their formative years tend have more
conservative financial portfolios through their lifetimes, reflected in smaller
stock allocations.
The restless investor has lost trust in the ability
of companies to undertake value accretive acquisitions or large capital expenditures
that have distant payoffs. Against the
backdrop of still weak revenue growth, higher discount rates and shorter
expected payback periods, companies have eschewed grandiose growth options and
turned to a new cost discipline to boost profitability. While a subdued nominal GDP growth
environment has undermined the ability for companies to achieve meaningful top
line growth, they are aggressively attacking their operating expenses and
deferring capital expenditures where feasible to boost margins and free cash
flow. And strong free cash flow helps to
support a sustainable lift in payout ratios.
Is there a risk that the restless investor’s loss of
trust and preference for capital now over future capital growth could undermine
the ability for firms to deliver sustainably strong growth in earnings per
share? Skeptikoi doesn’t think so. The new cost discipline is a welcome
development following decades where CEOs remained focused on growing revenues –
at times, at the expense of profitability and shareholder value. The renewed cost discipline will continue to
focus the minds of CEOs on what they can control rather than chasing the
pipedream of double digit revenue growth and market share gains that destroy
shareholder wealth.
Stocks with sustainably high payout ratios will
under-perform when the supply of income from the corporate sector eventually
outstrips demand. At that point, expect
companies to re-engage their growth options more aggressively, which will put a
smile back on the faces of the shrinking army of downtrodden investment
bankers.
But if market gyrations are any guide, the journey
to equilibrium is rarely seamless or linear.
Do not discount the role that the disappointing global cycle in recent
years has played in fostering the rise of the restless investor. The IMF and other forecasters have
consistently downgraded world growth prospects since 2010. The IMF’s preliminary estimate shows that
world nominal GDP expanded by around 6.5% in 2013, down from 9% in 2011 and the
lowest annual growth in over a decade excluding 2009.
Skeptikoi is wary that material upgrades to world
growth prospects would raise the appetite for risk and be associated with
under-performance of stocks offering strong and sustainable yield. But the signposts suggest that we are not at
one of those junctures just yet. The IMF
is projecting global nominal GDP growth to pick up over the next two years to
around 7.5%, still weak by historical standards. And the IMF has a long history of producing
excessively optimistic world growth forecasts.
The persistence of large output gaps in many developed economies remains
a headwind and should keep central bank policy rates close to zero for at least
another year. Moreover, any snap-back in
risk appetite typically occurs when stock markets are very cheap, which isn’t
the case at present.
Looking through the vicissitudes of the global economic
cycle, the restless investor’s loss of trust will continue to constrain the
parameters of corporate financial policies for some time yet. Skeptikoi believes that the process of healing
from the financial crisis is far from over; we have only just passed the fifth
anniversary of the collapse of US investment bank Lehman Brothers. In the wake of the financial trauma of 2008, the
corporate sector is learning an expensive lesson about the asymmetric nature of
trust; it can be lost very quickly, but takes a very long time to re-establish.
Friday, 17 January 2014
The Conglomerate's Fall From Grace: Two Tales of Diversification
By the time he had stepped down from the roles of Chairman and CEO of one of America's largest and oldest industrial companies in 2001, Jack Welch was arguably one of the country's most successful business men, a CEO superstar. During the two decades he ran General Electric (GE), the stock rose 4000%. Following his retirement from GE, Mr Welch was in hot demand on the public speaking circuit; many were prepared to pay handsome sums to get insights on how he had successfully managed a global, sprawling conglomerate.
GE represents an anomaly to text book theory and the trend in recent decades towards corporate focus. Long gone are the days where it was common practice for firms to undertake mergers and acquisitions in unrelated industries to boost flagging growth prospects.
The development of Modern Portfolio Theory (MPT) through the 1950s and 1960s espoused the benefits of financial diversification; the value of corporate diversification is limited to the extent that investors can achieve diversification for themselves. But at the time, the reality of high transaction costs was far different from the assumptions underpinning MPT; it was expensive for investors for investors to achieve home made or DIY diversification. Corporates were all too willing through the 1960s and 1970s to help investors diversify by buying up target assets in unrelated industries.
By the 1980s, two developments had changed the conventional wisdom towards corporate diversification. It had become apparent to investors that the conglomeration of corporate America has failed dismally. Growth prospects for many diversified enterprises had not met expectations. The failure stemmed from a lack of focus and the inability of internal capital markets to allocate resources efficiently across often disparate and unrelated divisions.
Second, the growing institutionalisation of the stock market had made it easier and cheaper for investors to achieve financial diversification themselves. In particular, the launch of the world's first index funds in the 1970s by Wells Fargo and Vanguard was a game changer not only for the asset management industry but also for corporate diversification. The ability to access low cost funds that tracked the S&P500 index meant that investors no longer had to rely on companies to undertake diversification themselves.
By the early 1990s, corporate America had undone most of the legacy of the conglomeration experiment. Many diversified firms restructured voluntarily, selling off underperforming assets that were not central to their key competitive advantage. And where management refused to see the writing on the wall, capital markets obliged, in the form of highly geared and aggressive private equity firms. Some of these firms would spectacularly fail burdened by excessive levels of debt. But investors had already delivered their verdict; corporate focus had won over corporate diversification.
The Schumpeter column in the Economist magazine suggested recently that the conglomerate might be staging a return ('From Dodo To Phoenix'). After all, the prospect of still subdued growth in nominal GDP around the world continues to undermine the corporate sector's ability to achieve meaningful revenue expansion. Corporate diversification could help to boost flagging growth prospects and larger firms might be able to offer higher salaries than their focussed counterparts thus attracting and retaining the best minds the labour market has to offer. The internal capital markets of conglomerates can also reduce reliance on at times fickle capital markets.
But Skeptikoi believes that a sequel to the first conglomerate wave is unlikely for three key reasons. The costs of financial diversification have continued to decline sharply. The advent of exchange traded funds (ETF) has revolutionised the asset management industry by increasing liquidity and transparency, as well as further reducing the costs of tracking a wider range of country and sector indices. An S&P500 ETF typically attracts a management expense ratio of less than 10 basis points and can be traded on the market just as easily as a stock can.
Second, a loss of investor trust since the financial crisis has meant that shareholders have little faith in CEOs to undertake value accretive acquisitions, particularly in industries unrelated to their core focus. They are increasingly rewarding companies for returning cash or capital back to them in the form of share repurchases and higher dividend payments. To this end, Skeptikoi expects the trend towards corporate focus to become even more entrenched; more companies are likely to break-up and sell off underperforming and unrelated assets to boost free cash flow and cater to investors' insatiable appetite for income.
Third, the financial crisis has failed to revive the fortunes of conglomerates. If there was ever a time for conglomerates and their internal capital markets to shine, it was in the wake of the financial crisis, where external sources of funding either became prohibitively expensive or even dried up completely for smaller firms. But if anything, their prospects have continued to deteriorate. Emerging markets - where conglomerates are more common - have underperformed significantly in recent years. And the great aura surrounding GE is no longer. From the lofty heights of the credit boom where the stock typically traded at a 20% book premium to the broader market, it now trades closer to a 20% discount. It remains to be seen what judgement history will deliver on the legacy of GE's superstar CEO.
GE represents an anomaly to text book theory and the trend in recent decades towards corporate focus. Long gone are the days where it was common practice for firms to undertake mergers and acquisitions in unrelated industries to boost flagging growth prospects.
The development of Modern Portfolio Theory (MPT) through the 1950s and 1960s espoused the benefits of financial diversification; the value of corporate diversification is limited to the extent that investors can achieve diversification for themselves. But at the time, the reality of high transaction costs was far different from the assumptions underpinning MPT; it was expensive for investors for investors to achieve home made or DIY diversification. Corporates were all too willing through the 1960s and 1970s to help investors diversify by buying up target assets in unrelated industries.
By the 1980s, two developments had changed the conventional wisdom towards corporate diversification. It had become apparent to investors that the conglomeration of corporate America has failed dismally. Growth prospects for many diversified enterprises had not met expectations. The failure stemmed from a lack of focus and the inability of internal capital markets to allocate resources efficiently across often disparate and unrelated divisions.
Second, the growing institutionalisation of the stock market had made it easier and cheaper for investors to achieve financial diversification themselves. In particular, the launch of the world's first index funds in the 1970s by Wells Fargo and Vanguard was a game changer not only for the asset management industry but also for corporate diversification. The ability to access low cost funds that tracked the S&P500 index meant that investors no longer had to rely on companies to undertake diversification themselves.
By the early 1990s, corporate America had undone most of the legacy of the conglomeration experiment. Many diversified firms restructured voluntarily, selling off underperforming assets that were not central to their key competitive advantage. And where management refused to see the writing on the wall, capital markets obliged, in the form of highly geared and aggressive private equity firms. Some of these firms would spectacularly fail burdened by excessive levels of debt. But investors had already delivered their verdict; corporate focus had won over corporate diversification.
The Schumpeter column in the Economist magazine suggested recently that the conglomerate might be staging a return ('From Dodo To Phoenix'). After all, the prospect of still subdued growth in nominal GDP around the world continues to undermine the corporate sector's ability to achieve meaningful revenue expansion. Corporate diversification could help to boost flagging growth prospects and larger firms might be able to offer higher salaries than their focussed counterparts thus attracting and retaining the best minds the labour market has to offer. The internal capital markets of conglomerates can also reduce reliance on at times fickle capital markets.
But Skeptikoi believes that a sequel to the first conglomerate wave is unlikely for three key reasons. The costs of financial diversification have continued to decline sharply. The advent of exchange traded funds (ETF) has revolutionised the asset management industry by increasing liquidity and transparency, as well as further reducing the costs of tracking a wider range of country and sector indices. An S&P500 ETF typically attracts a management expense ratio of less than 10 basis points and can be traded on the market just as easily as a stock can.
Second, a loss of investor trust since the financial crisis has meant that shareholders have little faith in CEOs to undertake value accretive acquisitions, particularly in industries unrelated to their core focus. They are increasingly rewarding companies for returning cash or capital back to them in the form of share repurchases and higher dividend payments. To this end, Skeptikoi expects the trend towards corporate focus to become even more entrenched; more companies are likely to break-up and sell off underperforming and unrelated assets to boost free cash flow and cater to investors' insatiable appetite for income.
Third, the financial crisis has failed to revive the fortunes of conglomerates. If there was ever a time for conglomerates and their internal capital markets to shine, it was in the wake of the financial crisis, where external sources of funding either became prohibitively expensive or even dried up completely for smaller firms. But if anything, their prospects have continued to deteriorate. Emerging markets - where conglomerates are more common - have underperformed significantly in recent years. And the great aura surrounding GE is no longer. From the lofty heights of the credit boom where the stock typically traded at a 20% book premium to the broader market, it now trades closer to a 20% discount. It remains to be seen what judgement history will deliver on the legacy of GE's superstar CEO.
Thursday, 19 December 2013
The Most Dangerous Idea at the RBA: Monetary Policy Doesn’t Matter
“In
the end, though, firms and individuals have to have the confidence to take
advantage of the situation. They have to
be willing to take a risk – on a new project, a new product, a new market, a
new worker. Monetary policy can’t force
spending to occur.”
Glenn Stevens, Reserve Bank of Australia Governor, December 2013
Central bankers have been on a steep learning curve in the past five years. Concerns surrounding the liquidity trap associated with zero interest rate policies have given way to the growing realisation that monetary policy can still be effective and affect agents’ expectations, risk taking attitudes and asset prices through forward guidance and large scale asset purchases (LSAPs). Christina and David Romer from the University of California argue that the most dangerous idea in the Federal Reserve’s history is that monetary policy does not matter. They attribute the prolonged downturn of the great depression and the great inflation of the 1970s to policy errors committed by the Federal Reserve, stemming from an ‘unduly pessimistic view of what monetary policy can accomplish’.
Glenn Stevens, Reserve Bank of Australia Governor, December 2013
Leading up to Christmas, Glenn Stevens probably
feels that he has received an early Christmas gift in the form of a lower
Australian dollar. For more than a year,
he has cited concerns about a persistently high dollar as impeding
competitiveness of the non-commodity export sector. It has finally succumbed recently; at the time
of writing, it had depreciated by close to 10% against the US dollar since
mid-October and by 7% on a trade weighted basis. Whether this has been due to Mr Stevens’
jawboning is debatable.
But as Mr Stevens indulges into his Christmas lunch,
he might well feel that his glass is half empty. By his own admission during this week’s opening
statement to the House of Representatives Standing Committee on Economics,
growth has been below trend this year and he expects this to persist for a bit
longer yet.
Nor would this week’s updated Mid-Year Economic
& Financial Outlook (MYEFO) provide Mr Stevens with much reason for
optimism. On the heels of a dismal
outcome for nominal GDP growth of 2.5% in financial year 2013, the Treasury
downgraded growth estimates for nominal GDP to 3.5% in each of the financial
years 2014 and 2015, down from the preliminary forecasts of 5% contained in the
May Budget and well below the two decade average growth of 5-6%pa. If this outlook transpires, the RBA’s nominal
recession is set to extend for three consecutive years.
But his main concern appears to revolve around what
he considers to be the limit of his power as the country’s top central banker;
according to Mr Stevens, monetary policy cannot effectively revive animal
spirits and encourage households and businesses to take risks. Skeptikoi is shocked by this. Yes, monetary policy cannot force spending to
occur. But what is the role of monetary
policy, if not to influence people’s perception of risk and discount rates?
To better understand this, it is instructive to re-assess
the concept of the neutral rate of interest, originally developed by the
Swedish economist, Knut Wicksell. Monetary
equilibrium is achieved when the real rate of interest is equal to the expected
real rate of economic return. A lower
real rate of interest encourages businesses to borrow and invest, which leads
to inflation and conversely, a higher real interest rate is associated with
deleveraging and either disinflation or deflation.
Skeptikoi believes that incorporating risk into Wicksell’s
framework can better shed light on the crucial role that central bankers can
play to revive the private sector’s appetite for risk. Investment is still weak in Australia (and
most other developed economies) because discount rates or perceived risks are
high, which continues to pull down risk adjusted rates of economic return. Renewed capital discipline, and high business
and household savings rates across most of the developed world confirm that animal
spirits remain dormant. No wonder;
October 2013 marked only the fifth anniversary of the financial crisis, the
largest global downturn since the great depression.
Given the depth and breadth of the crisis, the
process of healing could take a long time to play out. A new and growing literature that marries
psychology with economics and finance suggest that macroeconomic developments
during a person’s formative years can shape their lifelong attitudes towards
risk. Various academic studies show that
firms run by CEOs who grew up during or around the great depression had lower
leverage than other firms. And stock
market participation was lower for investors who grew up during the great
depression.
Against this backdrop, it is reasonable to think
that financial crisis ‘babies’ (and those that have been adversely affected by the
financial crisis) will remain cautious for a while yet. People have either lost their homes or jobs, witnessed
the value of their homes decline or have remain employed but with a heightened
sense of job insecurity. Consequently,
people are implicitly applying still high discount rates to their stream of expected
future cash flows, which is depressing the present value of their human
capital. And the household sector’s
lower permanent income flows through to an underwhelming recovery of
consumption and still weak investment intentions of corporate sectors around
the world.Central bankers have been on a steep learning curve in the past five years. Concerns surrounding the liquidity trap associated with zero interest rate policies have given way to the growing realisation that monetary policy can still be effective and affect agents’ expectations, risk taking attitudes and asset prices through forward guidance and large scale asset purchases (LSAPs). Christina and David Romer from the University of California argue that the most dangerous idea in the Federal Reserve’s history is that monetary policy does not matter. They attribute the prolonged downturn of the great depression and the great inflation of the 1970s to policy errors committed by the Federal Reserve, stemming from an ‘unduly pessimistic view of what monetary policy can accomplish’.
The authors also draw parallels between prevailing
views of monetary policy since the financial crisis with the great depression,
regarding the ineffectiveness of monetary policy at the zero lower bound, as
well as the costs associated with non-traditional tools. But more recently, the Federal Reserve’s
announcement of QE3 in 2012 suggests that it considers that the benefits of forward
guidance and LSAPs outweigh the costs.
And other central banks have clearly reached a similar conclusion,
including the Bank of Japan, European Central Bank and Bank of England.
Glenn Stevens is clearly frustrated that monetary
policy’s role in promoting the recovery is not getting an assist from government
policies that facilitate higher productivity.
While monetary policy is limited in its ability to affect long-run
dynamics of productivity growth, it is the role of a central bank to prevent a cyclical
shortfall in aggregate demand or act to prevent any shortfall from continuing. Skeptikoi is afraid that the RBA’s timidity
and its unduly pessimistic view that monetary policy does not matter, will unnecessarily
condemn Australia to a prolonged nominal recession.Monday, 9 December 2013
The Bond Conundrum and Global Saving Glut Almost a Decade On
“…the available
information increasingly suggested that the economic expansion was becoming
less fragile and the risk of an undesirable decline in inflation had greatly
diminished…the Federal Reserve came to the judgement that the extraordinary
degree of policy accommodation that had been in place…was no longer warranted
and…signalled that a firming of policy was likely.”
Looking forward, Skeptikoi expects the global savings-imbalance to persist and believes this can shed light on the outlook for real interest rates and monetary policy. The depth and proximity of the financial crisis – October marked only the fifth anniversary of the collapse of Lehman Brothers – suggests that the healing process is far from over. Worldwide, the precautionary savings motive remains strong across corporate, household and public sectors, while dormant animal spirits continue to dull the corporate sector’s appetite for increased leverage, capital investment and new hiring. Against this backdrop, long-term interest rates are likely to remain low for an extended period. Skeptikoi believes that monetary policies in developed countries ought to remain accommodative – through ongoing central bank purchases of debt securities and strengthened forward guidance – to revive animal spirits and encourage dissaving.
One could be easily forgiven for thinking this passage is an
apt description of recent deliberations at the Federal Reserve. In fact it was delivered by the then Federal
Reserve Chairman, Alan Greenspan, in February 2005, following an eight month
period in which the target fed funds rate had been raised by 150 basis points (bps)
to 2.5%. Yet by February 2005, 10 year treasuries
were yielding close to 4% significantly lower than 5% in June 2004. Greenspan described the divergence in the fed
funds rate and long term interest rates as a conundrum.
Given the ongoing decline in long term interest rates since
then – US 10 year treasuries are yielding less than 3% at present – that
semi-annual report to the Congress in 2005 has become amongst the most widely
cited speeches from Greenspan’s chairmanship.
A month later, then Governor Bernanke attributed the
relatively low long-term real interest rates in the world to an excess of desired
saving over investment intentions. The global
saving glut could alternatively be thought of as inadequate or
under-investment. In a closed economy, a
country’s saving imposes a constraint on the maximum funds available to the
corporate sector for investment. In the
event of a shortfall in desired investment relative to the desired saving, the
excess supply of saving causes the price of money (ie. the real interest rate)
to decline. Conversely, when expected
domestic investment opportunities exceed desired saving, the real interest rate
rises. So in a closed economy, the
current account remains in balance and the real interest rate equilibrates
desired levels of investment and saving.
In an open economy, a country’s account balance is
equivalent to the imbalance between investment and saving. When a country’s investment exceeds its
saving, it can borrow from abroad, so national saving does not impose a
constraint on the maximum funds available for investment. Although the country runs a current account
deficit, its real interest rate is no longer governed by the supply and demand
for domestic saving. The ability to tap
into foreign sources of saving lowers the real interest rate relative to a
closed economy. Conversely, a country
whose investment opportunities fall short of its desired saving, runs a current
account surplus and is a net lender of funds offshore.
According to Bernanke, the global saving glut had its
antecedents in a wave of financial crises in emerging markets a decade earlier,
which raised the precautionary motive for saving amongst those countries
affected directly as well as other emerging markets unscathed. Developing countries swung from being modest
net users of capital in 1996 to being significant net lenders by 2003; according
to the IMF, these countries swung from running an aggregate current account
deficit of $68 billion in 1996 to a $150 billion surplus in 2003. The size of the surplus confirms that any
growth in investment opportunities during this time was not commensurate with
the sharp rise in desired saving to safeguard against future crises. In contrast, the aggregate current account
deficit of developed countries had ballooned to $212 billion by 2003.
Bernanke acknowledged that the new status of developing
countries as net lenders of capital to developed countries represented a role
reversal from the experience of most of the 1990s and a challenge to the
standard neoclassical model which says that capital ought to flow to developing
countries; their low capital to labour ratios yield higher expected rates of
economic return. What the neoclassical
model neglects is the role of risk. Many
developing countries have poor quality governance and institutions, including
vaguely defined property rights, and relatively under-developed contract
enforceability mechanisms and financial markets. Consequently, few of these countries have
successfully developed globally tradeable financial assets but have had more
success in developing income producing assets.
Following the end of the dotcom boom in 2000, the associated
steep decline in stock prices further reduced the appetite for capital
investment in the US and globally. According
to Bernanke, “…with desired saving outstripping
desired investment, the real rate of interest should fall to equilibrate the
market for global saving.” Ricardo
Cabarello from MIT draws an analogy between safe assets and parking slots; a
rise in the number of cars and contraction in available car parks causes the
equilibrium price of parking slots to increase.
10 year treasury yields have continued to decline since 2005
and are currently yielding less than 3%.
In observations earlier this year, Bernanke attributed lower long-term
interest rates primarily to a decline in the term premium with an assist from
falls in the expected average real short rate and inflation expectations. The term premium is the additional return
investors demand for holding a long dated bond as opposed to buying and rolling
over a series of shorter dated securities.
According to Bernanke, the lower – and at times negative – term premium has
reflected among other things, the safe haven status and deep liquidity of
longer dated treasuries which has attracted strong demand from foreign central
banks and governments.
Those foreign central banks and governments are still
predominantly from emerging markets.
Trends in current account balances confirm that developing countries
continue to save in excess of their investment requirements; their aggregate
current account surplus has grown to almost $240 billion from $150 billion a
decade ago. IMF data shows that the
developed economies are also running a current account surplus, the first of
its kind since 1998.
While Bernanke did not cite the ‘global saving glut’ in his
recent speech to explain why long term interest rates are low, it is clear from
developments in current account balances that the financial crisis exacerbated the
global savings-investment imbalance; a heightened precautionary saving motive
amongst developing (and now developed) nations, coupled with a dearth of perceived
investment opportunities in developing (and now developed) countries. Like the end of the dotcom boom, the financial
crisis has ushered in a period of capital discipline and cost restraint, and raised
companies’ propensity to either hoard cash or payout cash to shareholders in
the form of stock re-purchases and/or dividends.Looking forward, Skeptikoi expects the global savings-imbalance to persist and believes this can shed light on the outlook for real interest rates and monetary policy. The depth and proximity of the financial crisis – October marked only the fifth anniversary of the collapse of Lehman Brothers – suggests that the healing process is far from over. Worldwide, the precautionary savings motive remains strong across corporate, household and public sectors, while dormant animal spirits continue to dull the corporate sector’s appetite for increased leverage, capital investment and new hiring. Against this backdrop, long-term interest rates are likely to remain low for an extended period. Skeptikoi believes that monetary policies in developed countries ought to remain accommodative – through ongoing central bank purchases of debt securities and strengthened forward guidance – to revive animal spirits and encourage dissaving.
Looking through the cyclical legacy of the financial crisis,
the global saving-investment imbalance will diminish only when emerging markets
develop stronger institutions and governance mechanisms that reduce perceived
risk and encourage investment - particularly in much needed infrastructure for rapidly
growing populations. But this thematic
will take a while to play out. The
persistence of low treasury yields might no longer be a conundrum, but Skeptikoi’s
view is that another decade on, the global saving glut and low real interest
rates could still be with us.
Monday, 21 October 2013
The Great Disinflation
Economic historians and academics specialising in finance
and macroeconomics have been and will continue to be the main beneficiaries of
the financial crisis. Academics are
still debating the causes of the Great Depression; one can easily extrapolate
that academics will be publishing journal articles debating the antecedents of
the 2008 Great Recession in 2100 and beyond.
Skeptikoi believes that another phenomenon associated with
the financial crisis has not been as well documented as persistently high
unemployment; the Great Disinflation. Inflation
and inflation expectations have dropped below the central bank target levels in
most developed countries since around 2008.
In the United States, the core CPI (which excludes food and energy) has
followed three distinct phases in the past decade. From 2003 to mid-2008, the core CPI expanded
at annualised rate of 2.3%. This dropped
to 1.1% in the two years to September 2010 and has posted compound annual
growth of 1.9% since then.
Australia’s disinflation also commenced around the time of
the collapse of US investment bank, Lehman Brothers. The trimmed mean CPI – which excludes items
in the CPI basket that experience the most extreme movements – grew at a
compound annual rate of 4.3% from March 2007 to September 2008 before slowing
to 3.2%pa from September 2008 to March 2010.
Since then, the trimmed mean CPI has grown at 2.2%pa. So for three years now, underlying inflation
has remained at the bottom end of the Reserve Bank of Australia’s (RBA) target
range. This should come as little
surprise considering that the RBA’s excessively tight monetary policy coincided
with Australia’s deepest nominal recession in over two decades; nominal GDP
posted average annual growth of 2.5% in the 2013 financial year.
Labour market developments do a pretty good job of explaining
Australia’s disinflation. Nominal unit
labour costs – which are a measure of productivity adjusted wages – are
currently at the same level as they were in September 2011. Excluding the financial crisis, this
represents the longest period of stability since the late 1990s. The unemployment rate of 5.6% remains close
to the financial crisis trough and has climbed by close to 15% in the past two
years, the largest proportionate rise in over a decade, excluding the crisis.
Later this week, the release of Australia’s September
quarter CPI will once again bring into focus the RBA’s policy
deliberations. The consensus forecast
points to a 0.6% rise in underlying inflation.
The deprecation of the Australian dollar represents some upside risk;
the Trade Weighted Index fell by an average of 7% in the September
quarter. But movements in the currency
have become less reliable than labour market developments in explaining inflation
trends in recent years, possibly reflecting the strength of competitive
activity at the retail level.
Some commentators have suggested that the easing cycle is
over and are forecasting that the RBA will raise the overnight cash rate (OCR) as
soon as in the first half of 2014. A
number of recent developments have brought the RBA some time. On the local front, there has been a
post-election bounce in business confidence and auction clearance rates remain
high in Sydney and Melbourne. Meanwhile,
there is growing evidence of a synchronised recovery in world growth; the
chances of a hard landing in China have diminished, renewed vigour in
quantitative easing is having the desired effect in Japan (Abenomics) and the
United Kingdom (Carneynomics), economists are no longer downgrading growth
prospects in Europe, and have recently started to upgrade their forecasts, the
US recovery remains modest but on track, with tail risk of a default on
Treasuries having reduced for now, and the deferral of tapering has stemmed the
flight of capital from emerging markets.
But Skeptikoi believes that the RBA’s easing cycle is not
over. The prospect of a synchronised
recovery in the world economy is a welcome development for a small open economy
like Australia’s, and should help to support commodity prices and the terms of
trade. But the renewed appreciation of
the Australian dollar is already mitigating part of the stimulatory benefits of
improving global conditions. And mining
companies are unlikely to kick-start large capex programs, having sought to
educate the market over the past year of their new 'laser like' cost focus.
Despite the recent significant improvement in business
confidence following the Coalition’s decisive victory at the September
election, the renewed cost discipline that pervades the corporate sector will
keep in check growth in capital investment.
Feedback from the ASX200 companies is that they remain focused on cost
containment, the deferral of growth options where feasible and the return of
capital to shareholders to cater to the market’s insatiable appetite for
income. Consequently, dividend payout
ratios remains close to a record high, no mean feat for a country that already
had among the highest payout ratios in the world due to the low effective tax
rate on dividends. Of course, higher
payout ratios help to reduce the agency costs of free cash flow, an important
development in light of investors’ loss of trust in corporate governance
structures since the financial crisis.
A corporate sector that remains focussed on returning
capital to shareholders and lifting productivity to combat the prospect of
still anaemic revenue growth is good news for earnings growth and investors,
but bad news for the labour market and nominal GDP growth. The RBA reminds us that private
sector savings rates remain at two decade highs, that business and household
sector balance sheets remain in rude health and that both have the capacity to
lift spending and withstand an adverse income shock. The RBA’s key mandate at present should be to
revive the dormant animal spirits that permeate the business and household
sectors by further easing monetary policy.
But their reluctance to do so appears to stem from the misguided notion
that persistently low interest rates would stoke a future property bubble and
undermine financial stability.
Subscribe to:
Posts (Atom)