Axel Weber, Chairman of Swiss bank, UBS
Most people are familiar with Aesop’s tale of the boy who cried wolf. A bored shepherd boy amuses himself by crying wolf when there is no wolf. He does so twice and villagers come rushing to help each time, only to find that that there is no wolf. When he cries wolf a third time, the villagers believing that he is lying to them once again, ignore him; only this time, a wolf has set upon and scattered the shepherd boy’s flock.
The chorus of bankers complaining about onerous capital requirements reminds Skeptikoi of Aesop’s tale. Two banking and finance academics, Anat Admati and Martin Hellwing have recently published a book (The Bankers’ New Clothes) that exposes the myths surrounding bankers’ cries of wolf. Given that excessive leverage amongst financial institutions propagated the financial crisis, Skeptikoi strongly recommends the book to anyone interested in the safety of the global financial system.
The bankers’
common cry is that they are forced to set aside regulatory capital, which sits
idle on their balance sheet and could otherwise by lent to businesses and
households. The Chairman of Swiss
investment bank UBS suggests that there is a trade-off between regulatory
capital requirements and economic growth.
As seductive as this might sound, it is utter nonsense.
To
understand why, it is important to consider the basic function of a bank as
‘maturity transformation’. On the right
side of a bank’s balance sheet are its liabilities: wholesale debt
funding, customer deposits and common equity that it raises from shareholders. A bank uses these funds to lend to businesses,
households and governments. The loans
are a bank’s assets that obviously sit on the left side of its balance
sheet. There is a mismatch in maturity
between the bank’s assets and liabilities; its assets are typically long term
and illiquid. There is no transparent
price mechanism that reflects and conveys the market value of loans. In contrast, a bank’s liabilities are short
shorter term and liquid; for instance, customer deposits are either at call or
have a term of up to three years, while funds borrowed from wholesale debt
markets have a similar short maturity.
The key
function of a bank is to manage the mismatch in maturity between its assets and
liabilities. It does so primarily by
carefully evaluating prospective borrowers’ ability to make their loan
repayments. To this end, a bank might demand
some form of collateral from the borrower.
A mortgagee has to pay a minimum deposit or down-payment, while banks
typically impose debt covenants on business borrowers that allow the bank to
re-negotiate the terms of the loan if those covenants are breached.
Capital
regulation is concerned with a bank’s mix of liabilities. In banking, capital refers to the amount of
equity raised from shareholders and used to fund a bank’s lending
activities. Why would a prudential
regulator wish to impose constraints on a bank’s funding or liability mix? It gets back to a bank’s delicate task of managing
the maturity mismatch between its long dated illiquid assets (ie. loans) and
short-term liquid liabilities. A bank
that is heavily reliant on short-term funds borrowed from wholesale debt
markets can easily become vulnerable to a crisis of confidence if a large
enough number of business and housing loans it has written have defaulted.
Capital
regulation simply forces banks to have a minimum amount of common equity
(relative to total assets or risk weighted assets) in their liability mix. A crisis of confidence is less likely if a
bank has secured a larger share of its funding from equity or shareholder
capital, which Admati and Hellwig describe as ‘un-borrowed money’. As residual claimants to a bank’s cash flows,
a bank can cease dividend payments to shareholders in the event that it gets
into trouble. Common equity acts as a
buffer or shock absorber in the same way that a large deposit or down-payment
better shields a mortgagee in the event that the value of her house declines.
Bankers
continue to propagate the myth that that capital regulation constrains a bank’s
ability to lend and inhibit credit growth.
Capital requirements do not require banks to set aside capital to sit
idly in their vaults; the need to have a minimum amount of common equity in their
funding mix does not affect the asset side of a bank’s balance sheet, notably
its loans. A bank retains complete
discretion as to whom it lends to, and how much.
Even though
five years have passed since the collapse of US investment bank, Lehman
Brothers, banks’ capital ratios remain woefully inadequate. Basel III has imposed more onerous capital
requirements than its predecessors. Some national prudential regulators –
including the Australian Prudential Regulatory Authority - have imposed even higher capital ratios than recommended by Basel III. Nonetheless, the leverage ratio (common
equity to assets) for Australia’s major banks is typically no higher than
7%. That is, for every $100 worth of
loans written by a typical Australian bank, it holds only $7 of equity. In contrast, the median leverage ratio for
non-financial companies listed on the ASX200 is 50%! The pattern of over-leveraged banks is
similar for US and European banks, whose leverage ratios of around 10% are well
below non-financials of 40%.
Banks that
fund a greater share of their loans with common equity are safer and should be
able to better withstand a run or a financial crisis. Why then don’t banks hold more equity
capital? The answer is simple; taxpayer
funded guarantees on deposits and systemically important banks encourage banks
to take on excessive risk. And
government guarantees allow banks to borrow funds from wholesale debt markets
at cheaper rates. The lure of cheap debt
funding is far too tempting for most bankers and trumps any systemic concerns that high
leverage could undermine the stability of the financial system.As long as governments and prudential regulators continue to heed bankers' cries of wolf on capital regulation, capital ratios will remain dangerously low. Against ths backdrop, Skeptikoi believes that a crisis of confidence could once again expose the fragility of the global financial system.